À la carte Culture
Media reformers concerned about rising cable television bills and “indecency” advocates offended by cable’s titillating programs have joined forces in support of so-called à la carte cable which would allow subscribers to pay for only the channels they want to watch rather than pay set fees for packaged channels. This à la carte movement gained steam after the Janet Jackson reveal at Super Bowl 2004 when Nathan Deal, the Republican Congressman from Georgia, authored an amendment to a bill that would allow cable and satellite providers to offer channel subscriptions individually. The consumer advocacy groups Consumers Union and Consumer Federation of America joined the social conservatives from Concerned Women for America and Parent Television Council in a letter of support for the amendment. According to Consumers Union’s senior policy director Gene Kimmelman, à la carte would “help lower costs, increase incentives for quality fare, and give viewers the opportunity to not pay for channels they find objectionable or too expensive.” After failed efforts to reign in ownership alliances among cable systems and programming networks and unsuccessful attempts to reinstate rate regulations, Consumers Union turned to à la carte to stem cable rates that had risen 2.5 times faster than inflation since cable rates were deregulated in 1999. And cultural conservatives knew extending broadcast indecency rules to cable faced difficult legal hurdles, so à la carte emerged as an option to keep the heretical MTV out of the households that didn’t want it.
Most cable providers strongly opposed these efforts to tamper with their profitable, vertically integrated business models and editorial powers to bundle as they see fit. Other media conglomerates that did not own cable systems such as Disney also opposed à la carte because they made huge profits by using broadcast retransmission consent rules (Disney owns major market TV stations) to demand large fees and prime channel positions for its cable networks such as ESPN and the Disney Channel. But cable networks focused on African American and Latino-themed programming also vocally opposed the amendment supporting à la carte, fearing that their channels would be the first to perish under such a scheme. In April 2004 Alfred Liggins, chairman of TV One, the cable network targeting African American adults, wrote an op-ed in the Washington Times arguing against à la carte. A month later Debra Lee of BET, Jeff Valdez of Sí TV, Kent Rice of the International Channel, Mike Hong at Imaginasian TV and Rudy Ibarra from Outstanding Latin Entertainment wrote letters to the House Committee on Energy and Commerce stating that under à la carte their networks would never have launched without the guaranteed access to viewers needed to attract startup capital. At this time the Congressional Black Caucus joined these programmers in opposing à la carte.[1]
In reaction to this opposition the House Committee abandoned the amendment and asked the FCC to study the potential impact of à la carte. In the spring and summer of 2004 a host of civil rights organizations representing communities of color implored the FCC to dismiss the idea that they argued, in the words of the Leadership Conference on Civil Rights, “could diminish what little diversity is currently on cable and put minority and women programmers at risk.” Other civil rights organizations opposing à la carte included the League of United Latin American Citizens, the NALEO Education Fund, Allianza Dominicana, the National Hispanic Policy Institute, the Hispanic Federation, the NAACP, the National Urban League, the National Conference of Black Mayors, the National Coalition of Black Civil Participation, the National Congress of Black Women, the Minority Media and Telecommunications Council, and the National Asian Pacific American Legal Consortium. Women’s organizations also united in opposition, including the Sexuality Information and Education Council, the Global Fund for Women, the Feminist Majority, American Women in Radio and Television Inc. and the National Council of Women’s Organizations. Geraldine Laybourne, co-founder of Oxygen, strongly opposed the measure. Contrary to social conservatives who supported à la carte as a means to insulate families from television sex, fiscal conservative organizations such as Citizens for a Sound Economy, the Cato Institute and the Heritage Foundation invoked diversity issues in their opposition, but relied principally on neo-liberal dogma to oppose any government regulations. As the Cato Institute put it in its FCC filing, “this debate really comes down to the question of whether government should preempt an industry’s preferred (and quite successful) business model.”[2]
In July 2004 Booz Allen Hamilton released a report commissioned by the National Cable & Telecommunications Association that supported these groups’ assertions that mandated à la carte and themed tiers would reduce program diversity and raise subscription rates for those who purchased nine or more channels. Under the laissez faire ideologies of then FCC Chairman Michael Powell, it was not surprising that the FCC supported these findings that warned against government mandates. The Report’s conclusions were also partially supported by the US General Accounting Office’s October 2003 study. However, the social conservatives in the House Committee, and the vocal à la carte supporter Senator John McCain, who chairs the Senate’s Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation, strongly encouraged the FCC to continue studying the issue. Lending momentum for further study was Powell’s announcement in January 2005 that he would resign, and three months later Bush’s appointment of Kevin Martin to the Chairmanship, an FCC Commissioner who had made opposition to indecency a cornerstone of his television policy. So the FCC’s Media Bureau went to work on the issue, but instead of conducting additional research it merely revisited portions of the Booz Allen study and identified “problematic assumptions” and “biased analysis.” For example, the Bureau argued that the Booz Allen report mistakenly assumed that under à la carte, viewers would watch less TV and that diversity would not necessarily decrease because advertisers would likely find niche channels with paying subscribers more valuable. But the Bureau’s report seems most enthusiastic about saving money for “mainstream” audiences and increasing ratings for the most popular channels. Consider the classical economic supply-demand reasoning of this passage that compares current practices of channel bundling to à la carte:
“Some programming networks that appeal to mainstream consumers might find it more difficult to enter under bundling than under à la carte. As stated above, an MVPD [multichannel video programming distributor] carries a network only if it either expands the base of subscribers willing to pay the bundle price or if it enables the MVPD to increase the price it can charge for the bundle. As Example 4 shows, an MVPD may prefer to add niche programming that appeals to a small set of subscribers rather than add additional mainstream programming that provides greater total value to consumers if existing mainstream programming is sufficient to attract the mainstream consumers. The example shows that programming additions that enhance the value to existing mainstream consumers may not increase subscribership and may not allow the cable provider to increase the bundle price without losing significant numbers of non-mainstream consumers. Thus, some mainstream programming may not be provided under bundling, even though it provides more total value to consumers than some niche programming that is provided.”
Not only is the report unconcerned about the loss of “non-mainstream” programming, it embraces it:
“Finally, in its discussion of efficiency in the marketplace, the First Report fails to note that bundling may result in the production of programming for which the consumer value is less than the cost of production, leading to an inflated supply of programming. If a switch to à la carte eliminated such programming, the result would not be a blow to program diversity, as the First Report suggests, but rather a restoration of programming to an efficient level, more consistent with consumer value…. The marketplace will thus be able more quickly to shed unpopular networks in favor of popular networks under à la carte than under bundling and in the process become more responsive to consumer demand for better programming.”
So programming diversity is measured by the optimal number of “mainstream” channels rather than a broad array of niche channels? What this says to the civil rights organizations and “niche” channels such as Sí TV and TV One that are mostly produced and watched by historically underrepresented groups is that a properly “efficient marketplace” that is more responsive to “consumer demands” would mean a weeding out of these “over-valued” networks. As Patricia Williams has demonstrated, this invocation of the abstracted and culturally neutral individual consumer in neo-liberal justifications for policy decisions has continued to suppress the interests of historically marginalized communities under the guise of a “neutral ‘mass’ entertainment.”[3] Rather than define a mainstream culture that is oblivious to its dominant status across class, gender and race, against a ghettoized cultural “other,” as Williams argues, we need “a view of a market in which there are not merely isolated interest groups, of which the ‘mass market’ may be one, but in which ‘mass’ accurately reflects the complicated variety of many peoples and connotes ‘interactive’ and ‘accommodative’ rather than ‘dominant’ or even just ‘majoritarian.'” Indeed, it is channels such as Sí TV that might not have launched in an à la carte environment, a channel that reaches across cultures with English language programming such as Breakfast, Lunch and Dinner which provides diverse perspectives on issues such as prisoner rights and gay marriage – a recent peak at their Website revealed a discussion forum celebrating Cesar Chavez Day during this critical period when immigration reform is being debated.
But waiting for cable giants like Comcast (which owns TV One) and Time Warner (which owns Sí TV) to decide what constitutes diversity and how much we should pay for bundled programming does not solve the structural issues of vertical integration, the radically unequal distribution of advertising dollars for programs that include the perspectives of communities of color, and the class biases of subscription television in general. And while à la carte offers no solution to these structural barriers, the way in which the issue is framed can have implications for how we build networks and campaigns to address them. When the progressive Consumers Union and the Free Press support à la carte in opposition to a broad spectrum of communities of color, and they do so by framing the issues using the classical economic language of individual consumer choice (the title of a Consumers Union report supporting à la carte is, “Let the Market Decide”), we risk reproducing the abstracted, universalistic discourses of consumer choice and neutral markets that have reinforced current structural arrangements rather than invoking the cultural rights of historically disempowered groups and the necessity that we all interact broadly with cultural difference instead of walling off our television viewing through personalized channel subscriptions.
[1] For a narrative of these early developments see Public Integrity.
[2] For a list of comments from à la carte opponents see MediaZone.
[3] Patricia J. Williams, “Metro Broadcasting, Inc v. FCC: Regrouping in Singular Times,” in Critical Race Theory: The Key Writings That Formed the Movement, eds. Kimberle Crenshaw, Neil Gotanda, Gary Peller and Kendall Thomas, (New York: The New Press, 1995): 191-200.
Image Credits:
2. Sí TV logo
Random Surfer Thoughts
Great column, John. Thanks. I find it interesting how the movement has support, too, from a lot of viewers who “shouldn’t” be supporting it. What I mean is that many people engage in a huge amount of channel surfing, not always because “nothing’s on,” but just because that’s what “watching television” is often about. Yet many of the same people offer vocal support to a major change that would amount to making “watching television” into “watching specific programs.”
Behind this lies the peculiarity of how we (both viewers and analysts) tend to talk of television. Many of us enjoy TV as background, or TV as images and snippets. But when we talk about TV, it’s often just about *programs*. So, whether this sleight of hand is due to a performance of class sophistication, and/or due to pure forgetting of the many “putdownable” media choices we engage in (as Joke Hermes calls them), many of the a la carte proponents may be unwittingly consigning themselves to a substantially less enjoyable TV in the process.
Meanwhile, the column and the a la carte issue also point to how TV is not just about what we want to watch, but what we want on TV for others. It’s such a Third Person Effects medium, which sometimes betrays how many viewers will discuss what they want society to look like at the level of TV and what’s on, even when they’ve completely vacated the traditional political sphere.
Are channels moot?
Nice column, but to play devil’s advocate: might the a la carte debate be moot in the digital era? As DVRs, VOD, and iTunes-style downloading circumvent the reliance on flow & schedule, the role of channel is greatly reduced. While we’re not there yet, we seem to be heading toward an era of program-based rather than channel-based viewing. Thus the challenge for distributors will be not to get placement on cable line-ups, but to build awareness about individual programs. I would not be surprised to see this debate appear to TV historians in 20 years as quaintly irrelevant, like the film industry’s lobby against the VCR in the 1980s seems today.
Jason, thanks for the provocation. Good point that the transition to online video distribution portends a more fundamental transformation of the network-era economic model of scheduled channels. But the central point of the column was that while à la carte cable does not offer a structural solution to a video culture that continues to marginalize communities of color, the way in which the issue is framed has real implications for building a movement to oppose dominant neo-liberal paradigms for regulating the audiovisual industries across old and new media platforms. Progressive organizations like Consumers Union that in may cases fight the good fight, granted from a position of little power within policy making circles, also represent a particular history of “consumer” activism that has invoked the neo-liberal concepts of abstract individual rights and competitive market conditions in framing solutions to social inequalities. This conceptual framing obfuscates the cultural and economic forces that discriminate against collective groups, including Latinas, African Americans, women and the working class, and marginalizes the organizations that represent these group identity movements, as was so glaring in the pro a la carte justifications.
Just as we’ve seen invocations of individual consumer rights undermine collective identity movements in television policy arenas of the past, (i.e. consider the WTBL Jackson Mississippi case that Steven Classen so eloquently recounts or the television station ownership debates in the 1990s that virtually made race irrelevant to regulatory consideration as Patricia Williams has demonstrated), we should be all the more attentive to how these issues get invoked in the transition to online video distribution. Whether it’s through the classical economic speak that propels the marketing of video-on-demand services, or the pay-per-view models of cable and the i-pod that create class barriers of access, to other online video content that is supported by the very advertising dollars that have historically discriminated against supporting the perspectives of communities of color (only this time without the ability to skip commercials), the issues that pertain to the “cultural rights of historically disempowered groups and the necessity that we all interact broadly with cultural difference” are equally relevant and important to the economic models of scheduled channels or individually marketed programs. Along these lines, Jonathan Gray’s excellent points regarding channel surfing practices that encourage cross cultural encounters and Third Person Effects that speak to the importance of broad access to diverse viewpoints in liberal democracies are equally important in considering the policies and practices of online video distribution.
Unfortunately we’ve often had to wait for the historian, 20 years later, to amplify and contextualize the struggles of marginalized communities to challenge dominant neo-liberal policy frameworks. Perhaps we shouldn’t wait so long in framing these issues as they pertain to the transition to online video distribution.
[And by the way, surely you must agree that there’s nothing quaint about the VCR debates of the 1980s that produced fair use precedents and an historical case study for considering Hollywood’s current campaign to build draconian digital rights management regimes.]